Análise
muito interessante do nosso amigo Giuseppe Gagliano (presidente do De
Cristoforis Strategic Studies Center) sobre a génese da Inteligência Económica
em França (iniciativa pilotada por outro amigo comum, o Christian Harbulot), sobre
a fundação da École de Guerre Économique (ainda hoje dirigida por Harbulot) e
sobre o desenvolvimento do seu quadro conceptual.
*Gagliano Giuseppe, President of the De Cristoforis
Strategic Studies Center (Italy) | published by Modern Diplomacy
In
order for the intelligence to contribute to making the best strategic
decisions, it is necessary that the mechanism linking intelligence,
decision-making and actions should work smoothly.
Therefore,
it is important to provide a critical evaluation of the information and to
understand that in the information society there is a great number of
accessible sources.
In this
regard, the French Intelco project had this specific goal and turned out to be
a very positive experience. Funded in April 1993 by Christian Harbulot
and general Jean Pichot-Duclos, Intelco is a laboratory of ideas on the role of the
information in post-Cold War geo-economic power relations.
Intelco
was originally part of the Council of International Defense (DCI) that had been
granted full autonomy to start a debate over economic intelligence in France.
The
original six members of Intelco were sided by one or two other members
nominated by the DCI; Intelco’s main goals were 1) promoting research and
awareness on economic intelligence through conferences sponsored by the
Institute for Higher National Defense Studies and partnership with
universities; 2) direct support to institution and enterprises. Intelco
contributed to expanding the national debate on new frontiers of economic
intelligence such as information war and cultural interference.
Intelco’s
message encountered the opposition of those who refused to acknowledge the
concept of economic warfare and maintained that while war brings death,
liberalism creates wealth. Such a misconception can lead to wrong conclusions
like considering the Clinton system as liberal, when in reality it is a mix of
protectionism, diplomatic interventionism and special services to support U.S.
companies, abuse of power in controlling electronic fluxes (the United States
control 90% of the software industry). Besides, refusing the idea of economic
warfare can also favor criminal organizations that are increasing their
turnover.
The Intelco
experience aimed at raising the awareness on real problems in the people who
were supposed to solve them beyond ideologies and partisan interests.
The most
problematic hurdles Intelco had to overcome resulted from French cultural
inertia. Economic intelligence was regarded with distrust: engineers were not
familiar with indirect strategies imposing to perform invisible and transversal
actions; security specialists had troubles adapting their traditional approach
into a new context in which information is accessible to everybody. Intelco
had to face the antimilitarism of those refusing to admit that defense
operations could also be helpful to companies and ignored the role of the
Pentagon in protecting the economic interests of the United States.
Contrary
to what most ideologues maintain, capital holders and defenders of national
interests do not automatically get together and join forces. Despite its many
enemies, Intelco continues to develop the concept of economic intelligence,
which sooner or later will be integrated with the concept of global
intelligence as the complexity of globalization increases.
The
experience with Intelco led to the development of a scientific literature in
French on the use of information and intelligence in both private and public
sector.
The
cultural gap with the United States shrank significantly despite the fact that
state administration, academia and business have long ignored this issue. The
contribution this literature gave to the debate on economic intelligence is
very important since it puts into question the Anglo-Saxon approach – that is
usually narrow-minded and influenced by big corporations – and therefore
provides room for a comparative study of market economies.
According
to the United States laws and business mentality, companies must be free to
deal with economic competition through offering better deals. The facts proved
this assumption to be wrong. In fact, to protect the automobile industry from
foreign competition, all stakeholders of the U.S. economy came together
(companies, trade unions, federal authorities).
The
ultra-liberalism suddenly turned into a patriotic liberalism. The politically
correct propaganda promoted by the international institutions under the
Anglo-Saxon influence did not prevent Clinton to consider defense as number one
priority for the U.S. economic interests.
Another
achievement of Intelco was the creation of the School of Economic Warfare,
in collaboration with the School of Trade (ESLSCA); the choice of using the
words “economic warfare” instead of “economic intelligence” was driven by the
fact that the former is more impactful than the latter.
Companies
struggling with the competition attacks know very well what economic warfare is
about, but is very rare for them to realize the importance of the role of
information in developing their business.
The
functioning of the School of Economic Warfare was based on the following
principles: fighting spirit, teamwork, risk-taking, cunning. These principles
find their equivalents in some of the illness of the French society: fighting
spirit only for career goals, information that is not shared, little awareness
of the importance for the business world to join forces, risk-adverse attitude.
Globalization
requires companies to adopt all strategies necessary to protect themselves
against the encirclement techniques used by foreign competitors. Companies not
only need to promote their own products but they also need to consider the
destabilization factors that competitors or other opponents can put in place.
The School
of Economic Warfare aims at seeking solutions to these problems, but so far
it is just a drop in the ocean. If the French elites continue to ignore the
importance of a culture on intelligence, they risk leaving the world in the
hands of one single owner. Clinton created a state-led security system allowing
the United States to increase exports while creating and keeping hundreds of
jobs. Placing the intelligence to the top of this mechanism significantly
contributed to the expansion of the U.S. power, together with favorable trends
of the world economy.
EU
Commissioner Édith Cresson explicitly said that the United States need its own
intelligence policy in order not to be affected by the other states’ one. In
this regard, former French Secretary General for Defense Alain Juillet defined
economic intelligence as a governance tool focused on controlling strategic
information and aimed at increasing competitiveness and security for both
national economy and private business.
Two other
leading experts of economic warfare, Christian Harbulot and Éric
Delbecque offered their own definition of economic intelligence. Harbulot
defined it as the constant research and interpretation of open source
information with the aim of understanding the other actor’s intentions and
capabilities. Delbecque identified economic intelligence as part of economic
warfare culture, specifically in the competence – meaning the combination of
methods and instruments of surveillance, security and influence – and in public
policy that aims at increasing power through elaborating and implementing
geo-economic strategies and establishing collective control of strategic
information.
The
concept of intelligence here derives from its original Anglo-Saxon meaning,
that is a collection of information enabling to operate in different fields.
This understanding of intelligence is not related to the espionage Cold-War
techniques, in which information circulated only within a restricted group of
experts through the use of illegal means such as technological transfers, theft
of IT material, firing high-profile managers.
A more
detailed analysis on economic intelligence and the practical application of the
so-called economic warfare, reveals three main fields of action: the watch, the
protection of information and lobbying practices. In particular, the watch
consists in the surveillance of the economic reference ambient in order to
instantly detect possible threats or opportunities to seize; there are seven kinds
of watch: competition, trade, technological, geographic, geopolitical,
legislative and corporate.
The
states that are able to perform these practices are those which truly
experience an increase in influence and thus in power. This perspective
privileges the state capability to use this strategic weapon over the one of
single companies that use it in order to expand their trades and increase their
profits.
Since
economic intelligence can be considered as both offensive and defensive tool
(for example when it is used to either foresee an alliance between competitors
or perform disinformation operations), it is the crown jewel of economic
warfare policies, especially due to the importance of information in modern
economies.
In this
regard, it is necessary for both public and private sector to join forces. An
interesting model is provided by the case of post-WWII Japan, where the Japan
External Trade Organization started collaborating with the above-mentioned
MITI, which had a significant role in strengthening of commercial ties with
other states.
The
Japanese case is very interesting not only for its flourishing economic but
also for the cultural environment, where every citizen feels morally engaged in
pursuing the nation’s greatness through technological and trade primacy. It is
no coincidence that 10-15% of Japan national budget for research and
development is allocated to scientific and technical information. The United
States also adopts a similar strategy, although it tends to disguise it as an
official matter of fair competition. The U.S. administration has in fact
established a counter-intelligence service. Through expanding the CIA mandate,
this U.S. agency also plays an active role in industrial espionage and provides
companies secret information about their foreign competitors.
*Gagliano Giuseppe, President of the De Cristoforis
Strategic Studies Center (Italy)
Source: This article was published by Modern Diplomacy
Sem comentários:
Enviar um comentário